I
“What do you
think of Evangelii Gaudium?”
Not having
read more than a few snippets, and having avoided the brouhaha that followed its
release last November, I didn’t know what to say.
“Well, I know
the Pope's a faithful son of the Church, which rules out his being a Marxist.”
My friend
persisted. “But, what do you think about
his economics?”
“I haven’t
read the document in toto, and I won’t think anything about them until I do.”
Now, having
read and prayed over it, the first thing to say is that the document is not
about political economy. It “is not a
social document” (184).
It is about
the kind of Church Francis wants: a missionary Church, an evangelizing Church
and, especially, “a Church which is poor and for the poor” (198). It is longer by orders of magnitude than the
dozen-or-so paragraphs he devotes to the economy.
In keeping
with the example of Christ, and the uniform social tradition of the Church,
Pope Francis exhorts Catholics to serve the poor, to extend them a preferential
option, to think of them, to love and learn from them. Amen, Holy Father.
As we descend
from the Church’s undisputed domain, i.e., evangelization, into the realm of
socio-economic opinions, the best way I can think of to address the Pope’s economics is by way of a thought experiment.
In its final
part, entitled “Spirit-Filled Evangelizers” (275-280), Francis addresses the
mysterious workings of the risen Christ and his Spirit. Acknowledging that it’s
tough to keep one’s missionary fervor alive, he
urges us to trust the Holy Spirit for nourishment:
“It is true that this trust in the unseen
can cause us to feel disoriented: it is like being plunged into the deep and
not knowing what we will find… Yet, there is no greater freedom than that of
allowing oneself to be guided by the Holy Spirit, renouncing the attempt to
plan and control everything to the last detail and instead letting him
enlighten, guide and direct us, leading us wherever he wills” (280).
I would like to use the Holy
Father’s observations about uncertainty and disorientation, following the
promptings of the Spirit, and the need to eschew excessive planning and control as points of departure to discuss business and economics.
II
He is undoubtedly
thinking of derring-do evangelical exploits such as the apostle Philip’s conversion
of the Ethiopian eunuch on the desert road to Gaza (Acts 8:26-40). An angel had
instructed him to take that way, and the Spirit told Philip to go up to the
Eunuch’s chariot.
This eunuch
was a minister of Canda’ce, the queen of the Ethiopians, in charge of all her
treasure. By the time Philip was done telling him about the
good news of Jesus, he had baptized the eunuch. Such was the beginning of Ethiopia’s conversion to Christianity.
Isn’t that also how
business starts in some countries—in the ones where personal initiative is
allowed to breathe freely. Somebody gets a prompting, an idea in a
garage, and follows it. He looks for
money, finds it, and bam! An Apple
Computers, or a Hewlett-Packard, is born.
Suddenly, there is wealth, which funds future ideas, future births.
Suddenly, there is wealth, which funds future ideas, future births.
Unfortunately,
aside from one grudging and conditional concession to the “noble vocation” of
business (203), the Pope has little good, and much bad, to say about the current
arrangement of the global economy.
He sees inequality, structural injustices, and the idolatry of markets and money everywhere. He even takes a shot at "success and self-reliance" (209).
He sees inequality, structural injustices, and the idolatry of markets and money everywhere. He even takes a shot at "success and
His treatment
of economics reminded me of the documentary, Inside Job (2010), which pilloried financial deregulation for throwing
up to 15 million people into poverty again. How common for free market
economics to be pilloried for throwing people back into poverty without having been credited for pulling them out of poverty in the first place.
The Pope, for
his part, identifies the origin of the financial crisis in “the denial of the
primacy of the human person!” (55) While that may be true, denial of the primacy of the person hardly originated with economics or finance.
His
prescription: “decisions, programs, mechanisms, and processes specifically
geared to a better distribution of income, the creation of sources of
employment, and an integral promotion of the poor which goes beyond a simple
welfare mentality” (204).
By the time we
get there, we are conceptually a long way from trust in the Spirit (or even in
people’s basic decency (54)), and from “renouncing the attempt to plan and
control everything to the last detail.”
Let’s conduct
that thought experiment, now, with respect to evangelization.
III
I wondered what Evangelii Gaudium would look like if it addressed unequal evangelical results in the same way it does unequal economic results. If it did, would the document encourage more, or less, missionary activity?
Consider that
the Spirit may blow in Brunei but not in Bariloche; in Southeast Asia, but not
in South America. European prayers for vocations may yield results in the
Philippines, but not Rome.
Unequal apostolic
results could transpire for many reasons. Missionaries in the Philippines might
have the good fortune of gaining access to the nation’s Treasurer, like Philip
did. Perhaps family structure is more conducive to mass evangelization in
Bruenei than it is in the United Kingdom. Perhaps technological advances are marshaled
to greater evangelical effect in Bejing than in Barcelona.
There could be
a million reasons for inequality in
apostolic outcomes--none related to injustice--including
that the Spirit simply has reasons for it that we don’t understand.
Perhaps we won’t
accept a simple answer, for instance, that some approaches might conduce more readily to favorable results than others. The answer might even lie in an entrepreneurial culture that rewards experimentation and success
without punishing failure.
Imagine that Pope-Whoever
overlooks the aforementioned potential causes and simply decries the unequal outcomes (193). “Inequality, [he claims], is the root of social ills” (202).
His mother’s heart suffers at the lack of spiritual development in so many places when others are so evangelically rich; it bristles at perceived blaming of those who lack the results being gauged (60).
His mother’s heart suffers at the lack of spiritual development in so many places when others are so evangelically rich; it bristles at perceived blaming of those who lack the results being gauged (60).
He regards
this unequal distribution of evangelical results with trepidation, attributing
the lack of spiritual development in one place to its superabundance in another
(202). He views the hoarding of graces conferred as a grave injustice, as
stealing from those whose integral development is not so complete (57).
At length, he
identifies the actual cause of unequal apostolic success: unjust social
structures (59).
He prays for politicians who are genuinely disturbed by the unequal distribution of evangelical results to do something about it (205). Politicians are responsible for the common good, after all, whereas the zealous missionaries of Southeast Asia are merely concerned with their own particular good, and that of the souls they tend.
He prays for politicians who are genuinely disturbed by the unequal distribution of evangelical results to do something about it (205). Politicians are responsible for the common good, after all, whereas the zealous missionaries of Southeast Asia are merely concerned with their own particular good, and that of the souls they tend.
In our thought
experiment, the heaped-upon missionaries object that they are merely following
Jesus’s call to feed the hungry, to give the poor standing at their doors
“something to eat” (49). Surely, the
Pope can’t be chastising them for being fruitful, or, alternatively, for committing fraud (148).
Moreover, they
protest, the benefits of their successful evangelization will flow to other
parts of the world, including the impoverished areas, as those once evangelized
become evangelizers and missionaries, in turn.
The Pope is
wise to that defense, however: a crude and naïve trust in trickle-down theories
that have never been confirmed by the facts (54).
In charity, because
the Pope loves everyone alike (58), he points out to the successful
missionaries that they are in thrall to an individualistic, indifferent and
self-centered mentality. They need to be more humane, noble, and fruitful,
which will bring dignity to their presences on earth (208).
Concluding
that this grave inequality calls for grand redistribution and structural change,
a meeting is set with the President of a great power who professes to share the
Pope’s concerns, and agenda—despite his aggressive devotion to pagan causes.
Gratefully, this is only a thought experiment.
IV
Surely, some
faithful sons in the above-depicted scenario might differ, in good will, about
judgments made and courses exhorted, even while embracing the Pope’s vision of
a dynamic, inclusive Church and world.
Following the
Pope’s counsel, they might even seek to dialog with him, to urge that freedom is a better path than planning and
control, even if its workings are disorienting and uncertain, and the results
of its application are unequal.
Whatever the
outcome of my thought experiment, all believers could be comforted in the knowledge
that the Church was speaking within her sphere of authority when addressing evangelization.
Her opinions would enjoy not only the benefit of nonpareil expertise, but also
the guidance of the Holy Spirit.
Such
assurances are unavailing, however, where the Church’s
opinions enjoy neither of those crucial guarantees: in the culturally peculiar
realm of political economy, for instance.
The Church
speaks with moral authority when it addresses the needs of the poor and exhorts concerted charitable action. It opines at the risk of mischaracterization or rejection when it identifies socioeconomic causes, and urges that the
solution to their problems demands political restructuring of economic
arrangements, whether local or global, for redistributive purposes.
That
transcends moral theology. The Church can infallibly proclaim universal truths on moral questions because all persons, everywhere,
are the same in their beings. Not so in their cultures.
Though not
uncontested, America's is one whose political economy is constituted by democratic
capitalism, a tri-partite division of influence and authority defined by
limited, democratic politics, free markets and a pluralistic socio-cultural
system.
When the Pope leaps from the “cry of the poor” and the “suffering of others” (193) to calling for politicians to “break down the wall of separation between the economy and the common good of society” (205)--asking, “Why complicate something so simple? ... Why cloud something so clear?” (194)--I fear he is leaping over the sphere of civil society—intermediate institutions including family and the Church—which is where U.S. culture traditionally situates the primary responsibility for care of those in need.
When the Pope leaps from the “cry of the poor” and the “suffering of others” (193) to calling for politicians to “break down the wall of separation between the economy and the common good of society” (205)--asking, “Why complicate something so simple? ... Why cloud something so clear?” (194)--I fear he is leaping over the sphere of civil society—intermediate institutions including family and the Church—which is where U.S. culture traditionally situates the primary responsibility for care of those in need.
Many people
who, acting freely, and caring a great deal for
others--many even responding to the promptings of the Holy Spirit--built those walls that Francis exhorts us to break down. Not everything erected through money and
markets was built by the bad, for the bad.
Conversely, history is littered with economically hopeless structures constructed by zealous politicians in thrall to do-good impulses and the conceit that they knew better what everyone needed than the collective assessment of idiosyncratic, personal decision-making--i.e., the market--did. America's political economy is designed to make that difficult.
The Holy Father manifests an exquisite sensitivity to cultural differences in other contexts. For instance, “We cannot demand that peoples of every continent in expressing their Christian faith, imitate modes of expression which European nations developed at a particular moment of their history” (118).
The Holy Father manifests an exquisite sensitivity to cultural differences in other contexts. For instance, “We cannot demand that peoples of every continent in expressing their Christian faith, imitate modes of expression which European nations developed at a particular moment of their history” (118).
I pray that he
ceases to demand that we imitate modes of economic thought which Continental nations
developed at a reactionary moment of their post-industrial experience.
As the Holy Father, himself, commented, “[t]he message that we proclaim always has a certain cultural dress” (117). To be sure.
As the Holy Father, himself, commented, “[t]he message that we proclaim always has a certain cultural dress” (117). To be sure.
Since he bypassed
the opportunity in Evangelii Gaudium,
I wish, hope and pray that Francis will also practice cultural sensitivity in future
remarks regarding political economy.
V
In the real
world outside of my thought experiment, Church leaders would celebrate the
successes of missionaries without impugning evangelizers for enjoying them. It
would hold them up as worthy of emulation, and brainstorm how their example
might be duplicated elsewhere. Certainly, they wouldn’t criticize apostolic
successes in one part of the world just because they are not duplicated
elsewhere.
The Church
would not seek to deter those who reap fruitful results where they sow. It wouldn’t impede their continued development
by conspiring to harness it for the supposed benefit of a common good.
I wish it would treat economics and wealth the same way.
I know that
not everyone acting in the economic sphere is open to the promptings of the
Spirit, not by a long shot. Yet, the
Pope warns that not everyone acting in the spiritual realm is either: those
acting under the influence of spiritual worldliness, for instance (93-97).
That doesn’t prevent him from counseling us to renounce planning and control, to trust the Holy Spirit and to follow his promptings in freedom.
The Church's goal, it would seem, is to increase the number of believers who, following the promptings of the Holy Spirit, voluntarily serve the needs of others, including the poor; not to animate the political restructuring and redistribution of material goods.
That doesn’t prevent him from counseling us to renounce planning and control, to trust the Holy Spirit and to follow his promptings in freedom.
The Church's goal, it would seem, is to increase the number of believers who, following the promptings of the Holy Spirit, voluntarily serve the needs of others, including the poor; not to animate the political restructuring and redistribution of material goods.
If only there
was a charitable, loving and inviting way for Churchmen to exhort generosity and sharing in
matters of wealth and economics without acting “as arbiters of grace rather
than its facilitators” (47).
It might admittedly
be pride on my part (and, if so, I ask pardon) but, with regard to political economy
and the planetary disposition of wealth, it seems to me that the Church is a
long way from finding its Christian, loving voice.
The world of
my thought experiment would be deeply demotivating, rather than inspiring, to
those sons of the Church aiming to serve it wherever it leads. I fear that the same is true in the real
world concerning Evangelii Gaudium’s
treatment of economic matters.
I pray, then,
for the Lord to guide our Churchmen, and politicians, to inspire us to the missionary
goals that Francis has set, and to give them charitable words that serve the poor
without bashing the supposed rich.
I say, “supposed” because the rich will find ways to escape whatever new structures planners and controllers devise. It will be the middle classes of the world, not the rich, who pay the price for Francis’s dreams (192).
I say, “supposed” because the rich will find ways to escape whatever new structures planners and controllers devise. It will be the middle classes of the world, not the rich, who pay the price for Francis’s dreams (192).
No comments:
Post a Comment